Moving communism's economic mountains. Deng Xiaoping and Mikhail Gorbachev are trying to wrest their huge nations from economic ruts. The Chinese so far are responding more quickly than are the Soviets.

SEVENTY years into the Soviet communist experiment and nearly 40 years into the Chinese version, how do the two compare? China is still economically behind but accelerating much faster than the USSR. China has demobilized one quarter of its army, more than doubled average farm income and exports grain once again. It has created 2,500 joint enterprises with overseas Chinese and the West, has increased trade with the West, and has sent 170 times as many students as Moscow to train in the outside world.

In the long view of history, Peking is returning to economic orthodoxy, after a radical experiment in reorganizing society, much more quickly than is Moscow. Deng Xiaoping's reforms are apparently succeeding; Mikhail Gorbachev's are slower out of the starting blocks.

Why?

Now that Deng is phasing himself out as administrator, will his handpicked successors be able to carry through the difficult further stages of shifting to a hybrid free-market system?

Will the Soviet leader be able to push and wheedle a new lineup of bureaucrats and ordinary workers into accepting the personal risks of a supply and demand-driven market system?

The answers to these questions are not simple. No change involving a billion humans (China) and nearly a third of a billion humans (the USSR) is ever simple. Leadership of such vast teams into revolution, counter-revolution, or reform requires wisdom, practicality, flexibility, and good timing.

In broad terms, China was fortunate to have a leader possessed of those qualities at a time when its people were willing to be led in a sharply different direction. The USSR's leader shares some of those qualities, plus a great deal of vigor and charisma. But his people may not be at a similar turning point.

Let's examine the two great Communist reform efforts.

First, China. Deng came to power well prepared. He had already rehearsed his practical reform ideas in the early 1960s. He had been bounced from power twice thereafter for backing such heresies as incentives for farmers.

Deng had seen what happened when Mao Tse-tung's ``great leap forward'' instead leaped backward economically. And he had observed that the real leaps forward in Asia were those being made without slogans by most of the states around the perimeter of China.

In fact, the contrasts between the economies of North and South Korea, China and Taiwan/Hong Kong, Vietnam and Singapore were striking testimony to the success of the disorderly, uneven free-market system in comparison to the monolithic Stalinist system which Mao had adopted in China.

Just as important, a majority of the Chinese people were ready for the risks of economic reform. After nearly a decade of Mao's (and Madame Mao's) chaotic, often brutal, Cultural Revolution, it was hard to find many citizens who were not willing to move in a new direction. They were, moreover, willing to do so even if it entailed some risk of inflation; loss of subsidies for housing, transport, and food; unequal pay; bankruptcy, and even job uncertainty.

There was also a third major reason for the startling initial success of the Deng reforms. China still had a substantial rural farm population, despite the Stalinist/Maoist push into heavy industry. Deng himself was a shrewd peasant from interior Sichuan. He recognized that past prosperity in China had often benefited the coastal industrial strip, bypassed the interior.

So China's reform effort began by freeing up the farm communes. In six years after the 1978 start of the Deng reforms, average farm income had doubled. Word of this success quickly spread to the cities, preparing the way for the more complex, difficult, and risky urban industrial reform stage to follow.

That urban stage is still underway, beginning with light industry and including an experimental mix of joint enterprises, special free-market industrial zones, changes in commercial law, the beginnings of a stock and bond market, and thousands of small private enterprises.

Now turn to the Soviet Union for comparison.

Only one of the three factors involved in Deng's initial success was present to a substantial degree in the USSR: (1) Gorbachev, like Deng, is an able leader determined to bully and woo his countrymen to change course. But (2) Gorbachev is not able to use the success of farm reform and doubled rural income as an incentive for urban Soviet society. And (3) the Soviet people have had no experience like the Cultural Revolution to galvanize them into taking the risks that go with reform of the Stalinist economic system.

Quite the opposite. Although Soviet citizens realize that their economy has become sluggish and is falling behind in this high-tech age, most have perceived a gradual improvement of their standard of living. The Chinese have had the Cultural Revolution chaos to look back to in horror. They have had the doubling of farm incomes to look forward to as incentive. But the average Soviet citizen can imagine reform having different results. Housing, food, and transport subsidies would shrink, with resulting inflation. Job tenure would become uneasy. Before a worker can imagine the benefits of higher wages, bonuses, and better consumer goods to buy, he can imagine job loss or transfer if his factory does not meet new standards.

The Soviet Union once had some 80 million farmers tending an arc of fertile soil stretching from the Ukraine into central Asia. Stalin drove many of the best off the land.

Soviet society today is largely urban. Before coming to power, Gorbachev spent some six years in charge of agriculture, but was not able to stimulate the kind of success seen in China.

Pre-revolutionary Russia exported grain; today's USSR is an importer of grain. When Peking collectivized farming in the Stalin fashion, China's farmers were no longer able to feed and clothe the Chinese people. With the advent of Deng's reforms, China once again produces enough to be able to export (to the USSR, among others).

Ironically, the reform schemes of the two communist giants had the same roots. After Nikita Khrushchev's February 1956 denunciation of Stalin, Soviet economist Evsei Liberman wrote a critique of the inflexibility of the Stalinist system. That same year a Chinese economist who had studied in Moscow, Sun Ye Fang, published a similar critique in Peking. Mr. Liberman's reforms were given a modest trial in the early 1960s, then denounced. Sun's were picked up in 1977 after he, like Deng, had been rehabilitated. Deng's prot'eg'e and fellow Sichuan leader, Zhao Ziyang, heard Sun speak and tried out his ideas for worker incentives in 10 industries. That became the model for China's industrial reforms.

What are the chances that either Chinese or Soviet market reforms will last?

The usual answer to such questions is that it is difficult to tell. And it is. Who, observing the American and French revolutions, would have correctly predicted the subsequent course of either?

Some points are, however, clear.

Deng has maneuvered brilliantly to squeeze out his old-guard objectors and bureaucratic hangers-on. He has nearly completed demobilization of 24 percent of the army, to aid the budget. In the process he has installed a new, younger officer corps which owes allegiance to his ideas. Gorbachev has merely replaced some top marshals and kept his military under civilian control. Both leaders have used investigatory work by the official press to expose managerial corruption - and clear away opponents and bureaucratic dead wood. But newly installed bureaucrats sometimes drag their feet to retain clout and perks.

Moscow is at the start of an attempt to gain Western technology and know-how through joint enterprises and trade. China has already begun some 2,500 joint enterprises (although many are small). The number of Chinese in private business increased from about 140,000 at the start of Deng's reforms to some 2 million last year.

Deng has picked his successors. By tacking brilliantly with the political wind, he has seen them through several crises of old-guard resurgence.

As indicated above, new party boss Zhao Ziyang has long been associated with the reform program. And Peking has taken one step Moscow has not to assure next-generation support. It currently has some 17,000 students training in the United States, while the USSR has less than 1,000.

None of these moves has set history in concrete. It has been said that the Chinese conquer their emperors. Also, that the Czar himself is powerless against his bureaucrats.

At the moment, China's reform success seems more genuinely decentralized in origin. The Soviet program seems more imposed from the top.

The Chinese program may breed more grass-roots support. When inequities and worker uneasiness threaten reforms, such support will be needed.

Earl W. Foell is editor in chief of The Christian Science Monitor.

You've read  of  free articles. Subscribe to continue.
QR Code to Moving communism's economic mountains. Deng Xiaoping and Mikhail Gorbachev are trying to wrest their huge nations from economic ruts. The Chinese so...
Read this article in
https://www.csmonitor.com/1987/1110/aearl10.html
QR Code to Subscription page
Start your subscription today
https://www.csmonitor.com/subscribe